Two Centuries of Parasitic Economics: The Struggle for Economic and Political Democracy on the Eve of the Financial Collapse of the West

Business & Finance, Economics, Comparative Economics, Nonfiction, Social & Cultural Studies, Political Science, Politics, Economic Policy
Cover of the book Two Centuries of Parasitic Economics: The Struggle for Economic and Political Democracy on the Eve of the Financial Collapse of the West by Basil Al-Nakeeb, Basil Al-Nakeeb
View on Amazon View on AbeBooks View on Kobo View on B.Depository View on eBay View on Walmart
Author: Basil Al-Nakeeb ISBN: 9781370817610
Publisher: Basil Al-Nakeeb Publication: October 29, 2016
Imprint: Smashwords Edition Language: English
Author: Basil Al-Nakeeb
ISBN: 9781370817610
Publisher: Basil Al-Nakeeb
Publication: October 29, 2016
Imprint: Smashwords Edition
Language: English

For two centuries economists have dismissed the choice between morality and immorality as a personal preference, overlooking their opposite effects on economic efficiency, thereby, seeding the economic and political crises of the Western World. Hence, there is a need for a framework to expound and measure the effects of moral vs. immoral economic policies. Using the concept of externalities to develop a “unified theory of macroeconomic failure,” Two Centuries of Parasitic Economics provides a framework that rationally explains the causes of the deepening crises facing the West.
For example, economists have simplistically assumed that banning interest is a purely religious matter without economic implications, ignoring its considerable negative externality, whereas all deep economic crises are directly linked to excessive indebtedness, including the Great Depression and the global financial meltdown in 2008. Economists have underestimated the real cost of interest, which in addition to the nominal interest includes the phenomenal cost of the crises it seeds, including the loss of profits, tax revenue, and homes, the cost unemployment compensation, the escalating cost of bank bailouts, etc. Clearly, the public cost of interest far exceeds its private cost (the nominal interest), precisely the definition of a negative externality such as pollution, which calls for taxing interest to raise its private cost closer to its public cost to improve economic efficiency and optimize resource allocation. Still, academia has not called for taxing interest to encourage socially cheaper and more robust modes of financing.
More fundamentally, morality is consistent with the interest of the majority of society while immorality serves the interest of a tiny minority, typically, the wealthy plutocracy. Accordingly, promoting democratic economic policies is moral and economically efficient and vice versa. Thus, claiming that cutting the taxes of the ultra-wealthy while increasing the indirect tax burden on the majority provides trickle-down benefits is not just immoral but necessarily inefficient and irrational to boot.
However, those are hardly the only economic blunders. There is a sense of national pride in a strong US dollar as evidence of a strong America; neoclassical economists are guilty of underplaying this grave problem, fearing it could spark inflation. A grossly overvalued dollar is a negative externality, causing huge trade deficits that are approaching a trillion dollars annually. An overvalued currency is tantamount to a tax on exports combined with an imports subsidy. Consequently, the US has been rapidly losing its industrial and tax bases and its high-paying jobs, while its growth has faded.
Another moral and economic issue is the level of wages. In general, neoclassical economists and businesspeople oppose higher wages as detrimental to profits. This position has validity when using static microeconomic analysis. However, at the macro, dynamic, level the opposite is true: higher wages, by overcoming chronic underconsumption, expand markets, permit the realization of economies of scale, increase profits, expand the production possibility frontier of an economy, and spur economic growth. A century and a half ago, the economic policies of Chancellor Otto von Bismarck demonstrated as much, permitting German industrial production to overtake that of France and Great Britain in record time, stunning classical British and French economists. Similarly, the sharp rise in wages following World War II fueled the longest and fastest economic boom on record in America.
In the final analysis, improving economic efficiency must begin by overhauling the democratic process itself, to make it more competitive, fairer and insulated from the influence of money. Only then could endless wars of aggression that benefit the war profiteers stop, monopoly fade and competition and the welfare state flourish.

View on Amazon View on AbeBooks View on Kobo View on B.Depository View on eBay View on Walmart

For two centuries economists have dismissed the choice between morality and immorality as a personal preference, overlooking their opposite effects on economic efficiency, thereby, seeding the economic and political crises of the Western World. Hence, there is a need for a framework to expound and measure the effects of moral vs. immoral economic policies. Using the concept of externalities to develop a “unified theory of macroeconomic failure,” Two Centuries of Parasitic Economics provides a framework that rationally explains the causes of the deepening crises facing the West.
For example, economists have simplistically assumed that banning interest is a purely religious matter without economic implications, ignoring its considerable negative externality, whereas all deep economic crises are directly linked to excessive indebtedness, including the Great Depression and the global financial meltdown in 2008. Economists have underestimated the real cost of interest, which in addition to the nominal interest includes the phenomenal cost of the crises it seeds, including the loss of profits, tax revenue, and homes, the cost unemployment compensation, the escalating cost of bank bailouts, etc. Clearly, the public cost of interest far exceeds its private cost (the nominal interest), precisely the definition of a negative externality such as pollution, which calls for taxing interest to raise its private cost closer to its public cost to improve economic efficiency and optimize resource allocation. Still, academia has not called for taxing interest to encourage socially cheaper and more robust modes of financing.
More fundamentally, morality is consistent with the interest of the majority of society while immorality serves the interest of a tiny minority, typically, the wealthy plutocracy. Accordingly, promoting democratic economic policies is moral and economically efficient and vice versa. Thus, claiming that cutting the taxes of the ultra-wealthy while increasing the indirect tax burden on the majority provides trickle-down benefits is not just immoral but necessarily inefficient and irrational to boot.
However, those are hardly the only economic blunders. There is a sense of national pride in a strong US dollar as evidence of a strong America; neoclassical economists are guilty of underplaying this grave problem, fearing it could spark inflation. A grossly overvalued dollar is a negative externality, causing huge trade deficits that are approaching a trillion dollars annually. An overvalued currency is tantamount to a tax on exports combined with an imports subsidy. Consequently, the US has been rapidly losing its industrial and tax bases and its high-paying jobs, while its growth has faded.
Another moral and economic issue is the level of wages. In general, neoclassical economists and businesspeople oppose higher wages as detrimental to profits. This position has validity when using static microeconomic analysis. However, at the macro, dynamic, level the opposite is true: higher wages, by overcoming chronic underconsumption, expand markets, permit the realization of economies of scale, increase profits, expand the production possibility frontier of an economy, and spur economic growth. A century and a half ago, the economic policies of Chancellor Otto von Bismarck demonstrated as much, permitting German industrial production to overtake that of France and Great Britain in record time, stunning classical British and French economists. Similarly, the sharp rise in wages following World War II fueled the longest and fastest economic boom on record in America.
In the final analysis, improving economic efficiency must begin by overhauling the democratic process itself, to make it more competitive, fairer and insulated from the influence of money. Only then could endless wars of aggression that benefit the war profiteers stop, monopoly fade and competition and the welfare state flourish.

More books from Economic Policy

Cover of the book Economic Interdependence and International Conflict by Basil Al-Nakeeb
Cover of the book Wealth, Poverty and Politics by Basil Al-Nakeeb
Cover of the book Stimulate Job Growth During Times of Recession: A Quick Fix Guide to Unemployment by Basil Al-Nakeeb
Cover of the book Playing Our Game by Basil Al-Nakeeb
Cover of the book How to Combat Recession by Basil Al-Nakeeb
Cover of the book US Programs Affecting Food and Agricultural Marketing by Basil Al-Nakeeb
Cover of the book  by Basil Al-Nakeeb
Cover of the book Cómo conseguir la consistencia haciendo trading by Basil Al-Nakeeb
Cover of the book Dobbiamo restituire fiducia ai mercati Falso! by Basil Al-Nakeeb
Cover of the book La grande saignée by Basil Al-Nakeeb
Cover of the book Summary of The 48 Laws of Power by Basil Al-Nakeeb
Cover of the book Tea Party Catholic by Basil Al-Nakeeb
Cover of the book Argentina Since the 2001 Crisis by Basil Al-Nakeeb
Cover of the book Handbook of Public Economics by Basil Al-Nakeeb
Cover of the book The Politics of Autonomy in Latin America by Basil Al-Nakeeb
We use our own "cookies" and third party cookies to improve services and to see statistical information. By using this website, you agree to our Privacy Policy