The Great Divergence

China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy

Nonfiction, History, Modern, 19th Century
Cover of the book The Great Divergence by Kenneth Pomeranz, Princeton University Press
View on Amazon View on AbeBooks View on Kobo View on B.Depository View on eBay View on Walmart
Author: Kenneth Pomeranz ISBN: 9781400823499
Publisher: Princeton University Press Publication: July 1, 2009
Imprint: Princeton University Press Language: English
Author: Kenneth Pomeranz
ISBN: 9781400823499
Publisher: Princeton University Press
Publication: July 1, 2009
Imprint: Princeton University Press
Language: English

The Great Divergence brings new insight to one of the classic questions of history: Why did sustained industrial growth begin in Northwest Europe, despite surprising similarities between advanced areas of Europe and East Asia? As Ken Pomeranz shows, as recently as 1750, parallels between these two parts of the world were very high in life expectancy, consumption, product and factor markets, and the strategies of households. Perhaps most surprisingly, Pomeranz demonstrates that the Chinese and Japanese cores were no worse off ecologically than Western Europe. Core areas throughout the eighteenth-century Old World faced comparable local shortages of land-intensive products, shortages that were only partly resolved by trade.

Pomeranz argues that Europe's nineteenth-century divergence from the Old World owes much to the fortunate location of coal, which substituted for timber. This made Europe's failure to use its land intensively much less of a problem, while allowing growth in energy-intensive industries. Another crucial difference that he notes has to do with trade. Fortuitous global conjunctures made the Americas a greater source of needed primary products for Europe than any Asian periphery. This allowed Northwest Europe to grow dramatically in population, specialize further in manufactures, and remove labor from the land, using increased imports rather than maximizing yields. Together, coal and the New World allowed Europe to grow along resource-intensive, labor-saving paths.

Meanwhile, Asia hit a cul-de-sac. Although the East Asian hinterlands boomed after 1750, both in population and in manufacturing, this growth prevented these peripheral regions from exporting vital resources to the cloth-producing Yangzi Delta. As a result, growth in the core of East Asia's economy essentially stopped, and what growth did exist was forced along labor-intensive, resource-saving paths--paths Europe could have been forced down, too, had it not been for favorable resource stocks from underground and overseas.

View on Amazon View on AbeBooks View on Kobo View on B.Depository View on eBay View on Walmart

The Great Divergence brings new insight to one of the classic questions of history: Why did sustained industrial growth begin in Northwest Europe, despite surprising similarities between advanced areas of Europe and East Asia? As Ken Pomeranz shows, as recently as 1750, parallels between these two parts of the world were very high in life expectancy, consumption, product and factor markets, and the strategies of households. Perhaps most surprisingly, Pomeranz demonstrates that the Chinese and Japanese cores were no worse off ecologically than Western Europe. Core areas throughout the eighteenth-century Old World faced comparable local shortages of land-intensive products, shortages that were only partly resolved by trade.

Pomeranz argues that Europe's nineteenth-century divergence from the Old World owes much to the fortunate location of coal, which substituted for timber. This made Europe's failure to use its land intensively much less of a problem, while allowing growth in energy-intensive industries. Another crucial difference that he notes has to do with trade. Fortuitous global conjunctures made the Americas a greater source of needed primary products for Europe than any Asian periphery. This allowed Northwest Europe to grow dramatically in population, specialize further in manufactures, and remove labor from the land, using increased imports rather than maximizing yields. Together, coal and the New World allowed Europe to grow along resource-intensive, labor-saving paths.

Meanwhile, Asia hit a cul-de-sac. Although the East Asian hinterlands boomed after 1750, both in population and in manufacturing, this growth prevented these peripheral regions from exporting vital resources to the cloth-producing Yangzi Delta. As a result, growth in the core of East Asia's economy essentially stopped, and what growth did exist was forced along labor-intensive, resource-saving paths--paths Europe could have been forced down, too, had it not been for favorable resource stocks from underground and overseas.

More books from Princeton University Press

Cover of the book The Extravagant Universe by Kenneth Pomeranz
Cover of the book Connections by Kenneth Pomeranz
Cover of the book Partial Differential Equations by Kenneth Pomeranz
Cover of the book Euler's Gem by Kenneth Pomeranz
Cover of the book From Wealth to Power by Kenneth Pomeranz
Cover of the book Rewriting the Soul by Kenneth Pomeranz
Cover of the book Terror in Chechnya by Kenneth Pomeranz
Cover of the book Metacommunity Ecology, Volume 59 by Kenneth Pomeranz
Cover of the book War in Social Thought by Kenneth Pomeranz
Cover of the book On Rumors by Kenneth Pomeranz
Cover of the book The Phytochemical Landscape by Kenneth Pomeranz
Cover of the book Beyond the Beat by Kenneth Pomeranz
Cover of the book America in the World by Kenneth Pomeranz
Cover of the book Macroeconomic Theory by Kenneth Pomeranz
Cover of the book Bovids of the World by Kenneth Pomeranz
We use our own "cookies" and third party cookies to improve services and to see statistical information. By using this website, you agree to our Privacy Policy