Accounting for Value in Marx's Capital

The Invisible Hand

Business & Finance, Economics, Theory of Economics, Accounting
Cover of the book Accounting for Value in Marx's Capital by Robert Bryer, Lexington Books
View on Amazon View on AbeBooks View on Kobo View on B.Depository View on eBay View on Walmart
Author: Robert Bryer ISBN: 9781498536073
Publisher: Lexington Books Publication: September 7, 2017
Imprint: Lexington Books Language: English
Author: Robert Bryer
ISBN: 9781498536073
Publisher: Lexington Books
Publication: September 7, 2017
Imprint: Lexington Books
Language: English

Many scholars discuss Marx’s Capital from many perspectives, but Accounting for Value uniquely advances and defends an ‘accounting interpretation’ of his theory of value, that he used it to explain capitalists’ accounts. It confirms and builds on the Temporal Single-System Interpretation’s refutation of the charge that Marx’s illustration of the ‘transformation from values to prices’ is inconsistent, and its defense of his ‘Law of the Tendential Fall in the Rate of Profit’. It rejects other interpretations by showing that only a ‘temporal’, ‘single-system’ interpretation is consistent with Marx’s accounting.

The book shows that Marx became seriously interested in accounts from the late 1850s during an important period in the development of his critique of political economy, asking Engels for information and explanations. Examining their letters in the context of Marx’s evolving work, it argues, supports the hypothesis that discovering he could explain them with his theory of value gave him the breakthrough he needed to decide how to present his work and explains why, in 1862, he decided to change its title to Capital. Marx’s explanations of capitalist accounting, it concludes, amount to an ‘accounting theory’ that explains how individual capitalists and the capital market use what is, for many, the ‘invisible hand’ of accounting to control the production and distribution of surplus value.

Marx claimed his theory of value was a work of ‘science’, a critique of political economy that would deliver a ‘theoretical blow’ from which the bourgeoisie would ‘never recover’. He failed, critics argue, because his critique depends on hypothetical entities, which we cannot directly observe, such as ‘value’ and ‘abstract labour’, ‘surplus value’, which means his theory is not open to empirical refutation. The book, however, argues that he used his theory of value to explain the ‘phenomenal forms’ of ‘profit’, ‘rate of profit’, etc., by explaining the observable accounting principles and practices capitalists use to calculate and control them, in which, as he said, we can ‘glimpse’ the determination of value by socially necessary labor time, which experience could have refuted.

View on Amazon View on AbeBooks View on Kobo View on B.Depository View on eBay View on Walmart

Many scholars discuss Marx’s Capital from many perspectives, but Accounting for Value uniquely advances and defends an ‘accounting interpretation’ of his theory of value, that he used it to explain capitalists’ accounts. It confirms and builds on the Temporal Single-System Interpretation’s refutation of the charge that Marx’s illustration of the ‘transformation from values to prices’ is inconsistent, and its defense of his ‘Law of the Tendential Fall in the Rate of Profit’. It rejects other interpretations by showing that only a ‘temporal’, ‘single-system’ interpretation is consistent with Marx’s accounting.

The book shows that Marx became seriously interested in accounts from the late 1850s during an important period in the development of his critique of political economy, asking Engels for information and explanations. Examining their letters in the context of Marx’s evolving work, it argues, supports the hypothesis that discovering he could explain them with his theory of value gave him the breakthrough he needed to decide how to present his work and explains why, in 1862, he decided to change its title to Capital. Marx’s explanations of capitalist accounting, it concludes, amount to an ‘accounting theory’ that explains how individual capitalists and the capital market use what is, for many, the ‘invisible hand’ of accounting to control the production and distribution of surplus value.

Marx claimed his theory of value was a work of ‘science’, a critique of political economy that would deliver a ‘theoretical blow’ from which the bourgeoisie would ‘never recover’. He failed, critics argue, because his critique depends on hypothetical entities, which we cannot directly observe, such as ‘value’ and ‘abstract labour’, ‘surplus value’, which means his theory is not open to empirical refutation. The book, however, argues that he used his theory of value to explain the ‘phenomenal forms’ of ‘profit’, ‘rate of profit’, etc., by explaining the observable accounting principles and practices capitalists use to calculate and control them, in which, as he said, we can ‘glimpse’ the determination of value by socially necessary labor time, which experience could have refuted.

More books from Lexington Books

Cover of the book Sexuality, Rurality, and Geography by Robert Bryer
Cover of the book A Mindful Teaching Community by Robert Bryer
Cover of the book The Dialectics of Post-Soviet Modernity and the Changing Contours of Islamic Discourse in Azerbaijan by Robert Bryer
Cover of the book Buddhism and Postmodernity by Robert Bryer
Cover of the book Justice in the Marketplace in Early Modern Spain by Robert Bryer
Cover of the book Institutions and Incentives in Regulatory Science by Robert Bryer
Cover of the book Arguments about Animal Ethics by Robert Bryer
Cover of the book Muslim Europe or Euro-Islam by Robert Bryer
Cover of the book Campaign Finance Complexity by Robert Bryer
Cover of the book Conservative Islam by Robert Bryer
Cover of the book Advancing Critical Criminology by Robert Bryer
Cover of the book Dialogues on Migration Policy by Robert Bryer
Cover of the book The Cultural Career of Coolness by Robert Bryer
Cover of the book Refuge in Crestone by Robert Bryer
Cover of the book Motherhood, Poverty, and the WIC Program in Urban America by Robert Bryer
We use our own "cookies" and third party cookies to improve services and to see statistical information. By using this website, you agree to our Privacy Policy